It is acknowledged by Professor Galbraith and most other economists that the trigger event
of the Great Depression was the loss of money in the stock market. Investors were stopped out
of their margin accounts when the market suddenly declined. These margin
accounts were constructed by using broker’s loans (loans collateralized by the
securities purchased on margin). The
popularity of this type of loan increased substantially during the 1920s from one
billion early in the decade to more than 6 billion in 1928. A billion in 1929
is equivalent to a 100 billion today. Banks were not deterred from making these
loans since they could “borrow money from the Federal Reserve Bank for 5 per
cent and re-lend it in the call market for 12.” Not unlike the sweet arbitrage
the banks could make in the prelude to our Great Recession by packaging mortgage loans into
large bonds and turning a substantial profit by holding the bonds for a couple
of years. During both periods people realized there was a speculative bubble,
and that eventually the bubble would burst. This fact did not deter speculation
even though voices were warning of impending disaster. Paul M. Warburg of the
International Acceptance Bank in March 1929 predicted unless the “unrestrained
speculation” was halted an eventual collapse would “bring about a general
depression involving the entire country.”
The irony is everyone benefited initially from the bubble’s rise. Caution
was not a serious concern. There was a general feeling among speculators that
the market was supported by three strong legs. The action of speculators was
one leg of support for the market. The second leg was the upward
momentum of exuberant expectation of a continual rise. The third leg of support
was a general sense that there was nothing to fear since who would move to
deflate the bubble. In other words ineffective regulation was seen as support
for the market since the government was unlikely to act and everyone in the
market was benefitting from the rise. Unfortunately, no one stopped to consider how
other investors would react if the market turned downward and whether there
would be time to exit.
After the Great Depression, Professor Galbraith pointed out,
“it has become obligatory for the regulators at every
opportunity to confess their inadequacy, which in any case is all too evident.”
In March of 1929 the Federal Reserve Bank began daily meetings. They did not
inform anyone outside the Fed what the subject of the meetings concerned.
Suspicion and rumor focused on the stock market, but that was unconfirmed.
During 1929 there were some breaks in the market caused by rumor, but overall
the speculative stampede continued. Corporations and even wealthy individuals
lined up to provide more liquidity as the banks struggled to provide more and
more funding for brokerage loans. By that summer these loans were growing by
“$400 million a month.” There was concern
about the degree of speculation that these brokerage loans implied. These concerns
were dismissed as coming from people who “simply did not know what was going
on.” The 1920s were the period when Wall Street arose as an investment
opportunity for the public. It was a very immature industry without a history
and a culture of caution and restraint. This exuberance was supported by the highly-regarded
academic community. In the autumn of 1929 the foremost American economist of
the time, Professor Irving Fisher of Yale made his often quoted estimate of the
market, “Stock prices have reached what looks like a permanently high plateau.”
Irving Fisher’s comments reflected the fact that stock
speculation had become part of the culture. This trend during the 1920s
legitimized an activity that had not earned a place in the economic system
through trial and error. Likewise, in the Great Recession housing speculation
and expansion of the mortgage market to include lower and lower income
participants would also prove disastrous. When A&E launched the TV show Flip this House in 2005 starring Armando
and Veronica Montelongo house speculation or flipping was an accepted get rich
scheme. Two years later the Housing Bubble burst.
One of the most interesting sections in Professor
Galbraith’s book is his debunking of the suicide myth surrounding the Crash of
1929. He shows that statistical analysis supported a slight rise, but nothing
to justify the media's characterization of crowds standing on sidewalks waiting
for the next businessman to jump to his death. The media similarly misled the
public in explaining the cause of the crisis. Instead of looking at the
government they focused on finding someone in the private sector to blame.
There were Bernie Madoffs in the Great Depression, but like Madoff they were
crooks not promoters of speculation.
The real tragedy was the Press’ failure to understand what
happened and outline what to watch out for in the future. Professor Galbraith
made it clear in his 1954 summary, “It would be unwise to expose the economy to
the shock of another major speculative collapse.” Do you recall anyone in 2006 drawing a
parallel between the Housing Bubble and the Stock Market Bubble of 1928? I do
not. Why? It is because the gurus over complicated it. We would be better off
to simply look into get rich quick schemes and asset bubbles for the next
financial crisis rather than a trend line of monetary expansion.
There is no quick way to riches. There is only hard work and
slow steady returns. Blaming the cause of financial disasters on lack of
self-control or greed is counter-productive. These are characteristics of the
human species. Criticism is better directed at the people who create our
economic institutions and fail to structure them to constrain speculative
impulses and greed. Speculation is only a problem when the
economic system lacks proper controls. The problem is an economic system
without proper curbs, not people who lack adequate self-control.
When Professor Galbraith asks himself what the cause of the
Great Depression is he looks first at why business activity slowed. He finds his
answer in the unequal distribution of income. His argument is that if the
middle class had more money they could sustain the economy. Isn’t it much more
likely that with the financial shock of their monetary loss in the Crash
many wealthy investors lost their appetitte for new investment? Looking back we know private investment collapsed
reducing job creation and economic growth. These two factors are the
cornerstones of business activity. Professor’s Galbraith’s explanation lacks
credibility since middle class income levels did not change until after business activity slowed.
The Great Depression was led down and kept down by business people unwilling to
take risk.
What we can say definitively is that people lost money. Losing
money has quite an impact on people. Imagine a gambler from New Jersey arriving
in Las Vegas with hope and cash-filled pockets. He leaves his bags with the
front desk and goes straight to the tables. Six hours later he has lost 75% of
the money he brought along on his vacation. How enthusiastic is he going to be
to go back to the tables after dinner? This is precisely what happens after a
financial bubble bursts. The shell-shocked business people and investors are
not going to charge out of their trenches into the battle again. They are going
to hunker down, reassess and wait for a “real” opportunity. Professor Galbraith
misses the real causes of the Great Depression and misunderstands the pivotal
role of banking and business in making the system work. The problem is the
system, not the people in the system.
Rereading this book made me realize Professor Galbraith
focused on stock speculators and not on the characteristics of the financial
system which nurtured speculation. We now know that the crisis would not have
occurred if margin loans were disallowed. We also know that the stock exchanges
could have employed curbs to retard large daily movements. Risk curbs also could
have been created to protect novices in the market by tying their investment actions
to the facilitating brokerage firm. In other words, if the clients of a
brokerage firm lost a certain percentage of their client’s money, funds could be
removed from a reserve account required to be held by the brokerage firm to reimburse their clients for bad advice. This technique would tie an
investor’s risk to a firm’s risk, making both parties act with more caution. Another problem in almost all financial crises is excessive leverage. Leverage is easily regulated by market rules.
When economic conditions are not persuasive for business expansion investment is going to dry up. Without new investment an economy is going to slowly decline as loans are repaid and money is removed from the economy. It is not the potential for investment that matters, but actual new money coming from banks to create new business lines. More investment means many more jobs and more money looking for products to purchase. Whether this money is equally shared is not significant. One rich man spending an extra $100,000 or 100 people spending an extra $1,000 makes no difference to an economic system.
Seventy-seven years later a speculative bubble again
devastated the economy, an event we now call the Great Recession. The two
events are almost twins. The approach of the Great Recession could be seen by a
blind economist, but not by a sighted economist looking for help from a government regulator.
Sighted and blind economists before and after both crises
suggested fine tuning government action was the key to avoiding a repetition. The
whole idea of government action doing anything to improve an economy is an inheritance from Galbraith and Keynes. Their focus on government as our
financial savior implies the coach is more important than the players. It is
the team on the field that plays the game and determines the outcome, not the
coach. When the players refuse to play a loss is inevitable. Even if the coach
implores the players to play harder and the general manager increases their
compensation, if the players decide not to expend all their effort in a game, the team
will lose. Speculators did not cause either crisis. The economic field was not prepared properly for the intensity of the game.